Confronting the Coming Liquidity Crisis
SAO
PAULO – This month, G-20 leaders will meet in Antalya, Turkey, for
their tenth summit since the 2007 global financial crisis. But, despite
all of these meetings – high-profile events involving top
decision-makers from the world’s most influential economies – no real
progress has been made toward reforming the international financial
architecture. Indeed, the group has not seriously engaged with the
subject since the 2010 summit in Seoul. Put simply, the G-20 is failing
in its primary and original purpose of enhancing global financial and
monetary stability.
A big part of the problem is that the G-20 agenda
has become increasingly congested over the years. At a time of looming
financial upheaval, the G-20 must stop attempting to tackle a broad
array of issues simultaneously – a goal that has proved impossible – and
go back to basics.
The United States
Federal Reserve is now preparing to raise interest rates, which it has
kept near zero since the crisis. While monetary-policy tightening may be
necessary, it risks triggering a serious liquidity crisis in developing
countries, with a major impact on economic growth and development. That
is why, at this month’s G-20 summit, participants must focus on
providing a credible institutional backstop for the difficult times
ahead.
Specifically, the
G-20 should move to empower the International Monetary Fund, both by
pushing it to do more with its existing powers and by championing
institutional reform. Raghuram Rajan,
the governor of India’s central bank, emphasized this at the recent
annual meetings of the IMF and the World Bank in Lima, Peru, when he
called for the Fund to build a sustainable global safety net to help
countries in future liquidity crisis.
The necessary
institutional arrangement already exists: the IMF’s Special Drawing
Rights (SDR) department. Within this department, official entities can
exchange SDRs – the IMF’s own international reserve asset – for other
currencies. Moreover, the IMF can designate a country with a strong
balance-of-payments position to provide the liquidity that another
member needs. Through this so-called “designation mechanism” – which has
never been used – the IMF can ensure certainty of access to global
currencies in times of crisis.
Of course, if the
IMF’s SDR department is to become a global liquidity hub capable of
mitigating future crises, reform is vital. Ideally, major powers would
support efforts to strengthen the IMF. But the US has so far been
unwilling to do so, with domestic partisan politics spurring Congress to
block the relevant reforms.
While the G-20 should
not give up on IMF-strengthening reforms, it should hedge its bets.
Specifically, it should work with a “coalition of the willing” –
including the major emerging economies, concerned advanced countries,
and other developing countries – to create an institutional mechanism with which to respond effectively to the next global liquidity crisis.
One obvious option
would be to replicate the institutional design of the SDR department by
incorporating it in an agreement among the coalition countries. The Bank
for International Settlements, which was the counterparty in currency
swaps under the Bretton Woods par value system in the 1960s, could be
the manager of this system.
This approach
undoubtedly has major shortcomings. Indeed, the key advantage of the
IMF’s SDR department – that it is a quasi-universal and
government-driven system whereby currencies are exchanged with reliable
“collateral” (the SDR) – would be lost.
But the perfect
should not be made the enemy of the good. As long as an ideal system is
out of reach, an imperfect option will have to do. With the risk of a
liquidity crisis intensifying, and the existing international financial
architecture ill-equipped to respond to such a crisis, doing nothing is
not an option.
In recent years, the international financial system has become increasingly fragmented, exemplified in the proliferation of bilateral and multilateral currency-swap arrangements. For example, the Chiang Mai Initiative Multilateralization involves the ASEAN countries, plus China, Japan, and South Korea. And the Contingent Reserve Arrangement (CRA) was created by the BRICS countries (Brazil, China, India, Russia, and South Africa).
Swap contracts
involve pre-committed resources, which are not transferred to an
international organization with a specific institutional mission.
Instead, foreign-exchange reserves – that is, liquidity in currencies
accepted for international payments – are held in national agencies
until a swap’s activation.
This means that there
is no guarantee that, in the event of a crisis, a central bank will
actually provide the swap line it has pledged, at least not without
attaching political strings. In the CRA, for example, members can opt
out of providing support – and can request early repayment if a
balance-of-payments need arises.
Clearly, the world’s
ever-expanding network of currency-swap arrangements is far from a
reliable mechanism for responding to crisis. This is particularly
problematic for the emerging economies, which are especially vulnerable
now.
Turkey, which
currently holds the G-20 presidency, and China, which will take over
next year, should have plenty of motivation to demand action to create
safeguards against today’s liquidity risks. Beyond urging the US to
approve IMF governance reforms, both countries should be hard at work
building a coalition of the willing and designing an effective
crisis-response mechanism.
So far, Turkey seems
to be falling short, promoting an overcrowded and ineffective agenda.
One hopes that its leaders come to their senses fast, so that the
upcoming summit can produce the results that past summits have failed to
provide – and that the world needs more than ever.
Camila Villard Duran, a professor of law at the University of São Paulo, is an Oxford-Princeton Global Leaders Fellow in the Global Economic Governance Program, University of Oxford.
No comments:
Post a Comment